Sheng Xuanhuai

Name in Chinese
盛宣懷
Name in Wade-Giles
Sheng Hsuan-huai
Related People

Biography in English

Sheng Hsuan-huai (4 November 1844-27 April 1916), industrial promoter who developed the concept of company organization known as kuan-tu shang-pan [official supervision and merchant management].

Wuchin hsien, Ch'angchou, Kiangsu, was the birthplace of Sheng Hsuan-huai. His father, the gentry-official Sheng K'ang (1814— 1902), was a chin-shih of 1844 who held several minor provincial posts before becoming salt tao-t'ai at Wuchang in 1861. As a youth, Sheng Hsuan-huai undertook the traditional course ofstudy in the Chinese classics as preparation for the civil-service examinations, and in 1866 he passed the first examination for the sheng-yuan degree. Three times (1867, 1873, and 1876) he participated unsuccessfully in the provincial chü-jen examinations. By the time of the last failure, however, he was well on his way to prominence by another route. Like a number of other men who became important at the end of the Ch'ing period, Sheng Hsuan-huai entered public service as a member of the entourage of Li Hung-chang (ECCP, I, 464-71). After serving as a minor functionary in the Huai Army in 1870-71, Sheng rose to become Li's chief deputy for economic affairs in the years prior to the Sino- Japanese war of 1894-95. His first major assignment was an administrative post in the newly founded, semi-official China Merchants' Steam Navigation Company (Lun-ch'uan chaoshang chvi). Until his death in 1916, Sheng was intimately associated with this enterprise as shareholder and officer. He served as assistant manager from 1873 to 1875, left the company, and then returned in 1883. From 1885 until 1902, as its chief executive and largest stockholder, he was in complete personal control of the company.

In the last three decades of the nineteenth century, Sheng Hsuan-huai also carried out several diplomatic assignments for Li Hungchang. The most important of these were the negotiations for the recovery of the unauthorized Shanghai-Woosung railroad, the first in China, which had been completed in 1876 primarily with funds from Jardine, Matheson and Company. In 1879 Sheng briefly held a substantive official post as military-administrative tao-t'ai for the Tientsin-Hochien district. In 1880 he planned the organization of a joint stock company (under the official supervision of Li Hung-chang) which undertook the construction of China's first telegraph lines. This enterprise, known as the Imperial Telegraph Administration (Tien-pao tsung-chu), like the shipping company with which it had close financial ties, was to be Sheng's personal preserve until the telegraphs were nationalized after 1902.

From July 1886 until June 1892 Sheng Hsuan-huai was tao-t'ai and superintendent of customs at Chefoo in Shantung province. In June 1892 he reached the apex of administrative authority under Li Hung-chang with his appointment to the office of Tientsin customs tao-t'ai, the key financial post in Li's Chihli (Hopei) satrapy. In addition to controlling the Tientsin customs and serving as directorgeneral (tu-pan) of the kuan-tu shang-pan [official supervision and merchant management] shipping and telegraph companies, Sheng in October 1893 undertook the reorganization of Li Hung-chang's Shanghai Cotton Cloth Mill, which had been completely razed by fire. This enterprise was refinanced with private capital, in large part invested by Sheng and his business associates, and established on a kuan-tu shangpan basis with Sheng as director-general. Renamed the Hua-sheng Spinning and Weaving Company, it became the first successful modern cotton mill in China and served to enhance Sheng's position as industrial entrepreneur. Since 1877 Sheng also had controlled valuable iron deposits in Tayeh hsien, Hupeh, which were later to form a component of the famous Han-Yeh-P'ing Coal and Iron Company. With the fall of Li Hung-chang, resulting from the defeat of the Peiyang Army and Navy by Japan in 1894-95, Sheng Hsuan-huai's industrial and commercial enterprises gradually came under the aegis of the powerful Hu-Kuang governor general, Chang Chih-tung (ECCP, I, 27-32). During the decade of his association with Chang, Sheng's independent influence in Peking was significantly augmented and his economic empire considerably expanded. The first accretion to his industrial holdings occurred in_1896 when Chang Chih-tung placed under his direction the nearly bankrupt Hanyang Ironworks, which Chang had organized in 1889 as a government industry. With Sheng as a major shareholder as well as its chief officer, the Hanyang Ironworks and its associated mines were operated on a kuan-tu shangpan basis until 1908. Because of its continued inability to raise adequate domestic capital even with a monopoly franchise to supply iron and steel to government railroads and arsenals, the company increasingly was forced to turn to the Yokohama Specie Bank and other Japanese sources for loans in order to enlarge and modernize its plant. This development led eventually to the inclusion of a Japanese demand for control of the company in the Twenty-one Demands of 1915. Sheng continued to head the Hanyang Ironworks after its kuan-tu shang-pan status was terminated in 1908 at the time of its amalgamation with the Ta-yeh Iron Mines and the P'ing-hsiang Coal Mines—both developed by Sheng—to form the privately owned Han-Yeh P'ing Coal and Iron Company.

In October 1896 Sheng Hsuan-huai, with the backing of Chang Chih-tung, was appointed director general of the imperial railway administration, a new official agency charged with planning and constructing a railroad network as part of a renewed effort at "self-strengthening," prompted by Japan's easy victory in the 1894-95 war. Sheng continued to hold this post until the end of 1905, during which time the railway administration arranged for loans from European investors amounting to China $300,000,000 for the construction of 3,000 miles of railroad. When the agency was dissolved in 1906, a trunk line between Peking and Hankow had been completed, and a line from Shanghai to Nanking was well under way. Together with the lines constructed in Manchuria, which were not controlled by Sheng, these formed the basis of China's pre-republican railroad network. His position as director general of railroads brought Sheng Hsuan-huai into extensive contact with Western businessmen and diplomats and also brought him closer to the upper echelons of the Peking bureaucracy.

In 1896 and 1897 Sheng Hsuan-huai was rewarded by the emperor with sinecures carrying high court rank; in 1900 he was made vice director of the imperial clan court, and he gained the upper-third rank; in 1901 the empress dowager, from her self-imposed exile in Sian, appointed Sheng imperial commissioner to conduct the renegotiation of commercial treaties with the Western powers as provided by the Boxer Protocol. In recognition of his role in arranging the "Yangtze Compact," which secured the neutralization of southern China during the Boxer Uprising, Sheng was made a junior guardian of the heir apparent (t'ai-tzu shao-pao) in December 1901. It is because of this title that he is often referred to as Sheng Kung-pao in Western-language sources. In February 1902 he was given the post of vice president of the ministry of works and the upper-second rank.

During the years that he filled these numerous entrepreneurial and official posts, Sheng also found time to organize China's first modern bank in Shanghai in 1897 (the Chung-kuo t'ung-shang yin-hang, known in English as the Imperial Bank of China) ; to found and finance with funds from his shipping and telegraph companies two important centers of Western-style education, Peiyang College in Tientsin (1895) and Nanyang College in Shanghai (1896), both of which later developed into good technical institutions at which such political leaders as Ch'en Li-fu and Wang Ch'ung-hui (qq.v.), as well as many Chinese engineers, were educated; and to promote the organization of Chinese chambers of commerce in Shanghai and elsewhere.

Sheng Hsuan-huai was at the peak of his power in September 1902 after the conclusion of the (later abortive) Mackay Treaty, which was intended to set a new pattern for commercial relations between China and the West by raising import tariffs and abolishing transit duties (likin). It was just at this point, on 24 October 1902, that the death of his octogenarian father set loose a train of events that cost Sheng his official posts and the control of several of his kuan-tu shang-pan enterprises. The prime mover behind Sheng Hsuan-huai's discomfiture was Yuan Shih-k'ai (q.v.), who, having succeeded to Li Hung-chang's military and political power in north China, sought also to bring under his control the economic components of Li's regional domain. The telegraphs were nationalized; Yuan's appointees assumed control of the China Merchants' Steam Navigation Company; and only the strong support of Chang Chih-tung enabled Sheng to maintain his post as director general of railroads until 1905. Despite his losses, however, Sheng was able to protect his position in those enterprises, such as the Hanyang Ironworks and mines and the bank, which had not been associated with Li Hungchang. Until the dismissal of Yuan Shih-k'ai in 1909, Sheng was embroiled in a complex struggle to regain his power and position. With the aid of his enormous personal wealth and in alliance with Yuan's enemies in Peking, he eventually was successful. In 1907 Sheng recovered control of the China Merchants' Steam Navigation Company, and in 1908 he received the nominal appointment of junior vice president of the Board of Posts and Communications. But only toward the end of 1910 did Sheng return to official prominence in Peking and to de facto control of the board, of which he was appointed president in January 1911.

As head of the Board of Posts and Communications, Sheng Hsuan-huai again dominated the modern means of communications in China. His principal endeavor during 1911 was to seek the establishment of a national railroad system by bringing under the control of the Peking government uncompleted railroad projects which had been undertaken in the provinces by local gentry and merchant interests. Sheng's memorial of 1 9 1 1 particularly condemned the delays and corruption on the Canton-Hankow and Hankow-Szechwan lines as being injurious to the Manchu reform movement and to the national defense. The close association of the railroad centralization program with large-scale borrowing from the Four-Power Consortium contributed to a fusion of provincial xenophobia with growing anti- Manchu sentiments; and both were aggravated by extreme dissatisfaction with the proposed method of compensation to those who had invested in the railroads. Rioting in Szechwan and elsewhere through the summer of 1911 culminated in the Wuchang revolt on 10 October, which brought about the collapse of the dynasty.

Sheng Hsuan-huai was dismissed from office in the last days of Manchu rule and was forced to flee for his life to Japan. He returned to his home in the Shanghai International Settlement in October 1912. Until his death in 1916 he lived in retirement, but retained control of the China Merchants' Steam Navigation Company, the Han-Yeh-P'ing Coal and Iron Company, and his textile interests. The career of Sheng Hsuan-huai and the history of his enterprises are useful indices to China's response to the West in the last part of the nineteenth century. At the same time, the kuan-tu shang-pan formula foreshadowed the "bureaucratic capitalism" of more recent decades, one of the obstacles to the modernization of China within a democratic framework. Despite their pioneering character and the fact that they were few in number, the kuan-tu shang-pan companies controlled by Sheng showed a remarkable range and diversity. Heavy industry (coal and iron mines, a steel plant), light manufacturing (textile mills), communications (a steamship company, telegraphs, railroads), and finance (a modern bank) were all represented. It was undeniably a substantial achievement for one man to have pioneered in all these fields, especially in the unpropitious environment of late Ch'ing China. It was all the more notable that Sheng was able to undertake and manage these enterprises while pursuing an active official career. His industrial enterprises, however, did not signify the beginning of a basic transformation of the Chinese economy. On the contrary, their constitution represented a compromise with traditional Chinese institutions and patterns of behavior. Their opportunities for expansion were circumscribed by foreign economic pressure, by official indifference if not outright rapacity, by capital and personnel shortages, and by a framework of values that emphasized personal and family ties rather than rationalized economic activity. These enterprises inevitably were forced to depend upon the monopoly patents their official patrons had been able to secure for them. These monopolies could be relied upon to sustain the profits and perquisites and to protect the capital of the promoters, but they were not compatible with reinvestment of profits and long-range growth. In short, after an initial period of expansion, the modern enterprises founded by Sheng Hsuan-huai tended to be transformed into institutions for the protection of bureaucratic capital./p>

Biography in Chinese

盛宣怀
盛宣怀(1844.11.4—1916.4.27),实业家,发展了以官督商办为名的公司组织的观念。
盛宣怀,出生于江苏常州武进县,父亲盛康(1814—1902),是1844年进士,做过几任小官,1861年任武昌盐法道。盛宣怀幼读经书以应科举,1866年成秀才,1867、1873、1876年三次应举人试未中。但他最后一次落第时,在另一方面已很有发展。
盛宣怀像清末的一批名人一样,以进入李鸿章幕府开始自己的公务生活。1870—71年在淮军做小官,1894—95年中日战争前已升至为李鸿章处理经济事务的副手。其最初的一个重要任命,是在新创办的轮船招商局担任管理职务。盛宣怀始终是该局的大股东和主管人,直至1916年去世。1873—1875年,盛宣怀任招商局督办,一度离去,1883年又回任,自1885年至1902年,他作为最大的股东和主要负责人,使招商局一直在他控制之中。
十九世纪最后三十年中,盛宣怀曾为李鸿章处理对外交涉事务,其中最重要的就是谈判收回未来经许可修筑的淞沪铁路。这是中国的第一条铁路,由怡和洋行投资于1876年建成。1879年,盛宣怀正式担任官职,任天津河间兵备道。1880年,他筹建一个联合股票公司(置于李鸿章的正式监督之下),负责建立中国第一条电报线路。这个公司即电报总局,与轮船公司有密切的财务往来,也由盛经管,直至1902年电报总局收归国有。
1886年7月至1892年6月,盛宣怀任芝罘海关道。1892年6月,他担任了他在李鸿章手下最高的行政职务,当了天津海关道,这是李鸿章控制直隶(河北)管辖权的关键性财政岗位。除控制天津海关和担任官督商办的招商局和电报局的督办外,1893年10月,盛宣怀着手恢复为火灾夷平的李鸿章的上海织布局。这个企业由私人资本投资,其中大部分来自盛及其合作者,并成为官督商办企业,以盛宣怀为督办,取名华盛纺织公司,是国内第一个经营成功的纺织厂,并从而提高了盛宣怀作为实业家的地位。自1877年起,盛宣怀已控制了湖北大冶的铁矿,以后就此创办了汉冶萍煤铁公司。
1894—95年中国对日作战,北洋的水师和陆军都遭失败,李鸿章于是下台,盛宣怀经办的工商企业逐渐转归湖广总督张之洞保护。在他和张之洞十多年的合作期间,他本人在北京的声势尤为增强,他的经济王国也有很大扩展。他的工业财富的第一次增加发生在1896年。当时张之洞将1889年起官办而连年亏损的汉阳铁工厂接管过来。盛宣怀是主要股东和负责人,他把汉阳铁工厂及其附属各矿改为官督商办直至1908年。该企业虽获有向政府的铁路和兵工厂供应钢铁的垄断特许,但由于得不得足够的国内资本,公司被迫向日本横滨正金银行等日方机构贷款,以便扩大生产,改进设备。事态发展到在1915年的“二十一条”中,日方提出要求接管汉阳铁工厂。1908年汉阳铁工厂官督商办期限终止,与大冶铁矿和萍乡煤矿——均为盛所发展——合并组成汉冶萍煤铁公司,盛仍主持汉阳铁工厂。
1896年10月,经张之洞推荐,盛宣怀督办铁路总公司。该公司负责计划和建设铁路网,作为“自强”努力的一部分。这种努力因中国在中日战争中战败而得到促进。盛任此职到1905年止,当时已向西欧贷款三亿元以备建筑铁路三千英里之用。1906年铁路总公司撤销吋,京汉铁路已建成,沪宁路正在兴建,又加上不是由盛宣怀控制的东北的铁路。这些构成了民国前的全部铁路系统。盛宣怀身为铁路督办,得以与西方实业界和外交界广泛接触,并有机会侧身于北京的大官僚之中。
1896、1897年间,盛宣怀被皇帝授以宫廷闲差。1900年他被授予正三品太常寺少卿,大理寺少卿。1901年,慈禧由逃亡的驻地西安下旨授盛商税事务大臣,办理由辛丑和约规定的事务。12月,又因他在义和团起义期间提倡“东南互保”保证了华南的中立有功,授以太子少保,因此西方书报中就经常称他为盛宫保。1902年2月,他被授予正二品、工部左侍郎。
盛宣怀经营多种实业和担任官职的同时,还于1897年在上海创办了中国第一家银行“中国通商银行”(英国人称为“中国帝国银行”),又用轮船和电报公司的经费创办两所西式教育中心:天津北洋大学(1895)和上海南洋大学(1896),这两个学校以后都成为优良的技术学校,培养了如陈立夫、王宠惠这样一些政界人物和许多工程技术人才;还着手改进上海和别的地方的商务局。
1902年9月盛宣怀的权力达于顶峰,当时他签订了(以后流产)马凯条约。这个条约旨在增加进口税和取消中间税(厘金),为中西商业关系树立新的榜样。也就在这时,10月24日他八十岁老父死去,引起了一系列事故,使他丧失了官职和不少官督商办的工矿企业。导致盛宣怀衰落的主要推动者是袁世凯,袁承袭了李鸿章在华北的军政势力,又想进一步囊括其经济势力:对电报事业实行国有,由袁的亲信主管轮船招商局。幸有张之洞的有力支持,才使盛得以保留铁路督办之职直至1905年。虽然遭受了这些损失,盛宣怀仍能控制原非李鸿章所办的企业,如汉阳铁工厂、矿山和银行等。
1909年,袁世凯免职,盛宣怀卷入了夺回权力和地位的斗争。他凭借个人的财力并与反袁人士相结合,终于在1907年收回了轮船招商局。1908年盛被授以邮传部侍郎。但是直到1910年年底,他才回到北京就任显赫的官职并在事实上控制了邮传部,1911年1月他被授予邮传部尚书之职。
盛宣怀被授予邮传部大臣后,再一次掌管了中国现代化交通工具。他准备在1911年将原由各省绅商投资修筑而未竣工的铁路收归国有,以建立一个全国铁路网。他在1911年所作的记事录里,特别谴责京汉、川汉两路工程迟缓和路政腐败,以致贻误清廷的改良运动和防务。他主张铁路收回国有,同时又向四国银团大量借款,激起各省的仇外和排满情绪。而且当时提出的对筑路股款的补偿办法更增强了人们的极度不满。1911年夏四川等地纷纷起事,接着10月10日武昌起义,清朝遂告覆亡。
盛宣怀在清朝最后一段时间免职,被迫逃往日本,1912年10月又回到上海公共租界寓所。他在上海赋闲直至1916年去世,但仍保持着对招商局、汉冶萍煤铁公司及其他一些纺织厂的控制权。
盛宣怀的经历及其创办企业的历史,是十九世纪末中国对西方的反应的一个有用的索引。同时,盛宣怀的官督商办的方式又预示了近几十年“官僚资本主义”的出现,官僚资本主义阻挠中国按民主模式实行现代化。尽管盛宣怀所办企业具有创业性质,而且为数不多,但他这种官督商办企业涉及范围很广,种类很多,重工业的煤铁矿和一个钢厂,轻工业的纺织厂,交通业的轮船、铁路、电报,财政金融业的一家近代银行,这种种都包括进去了。就一个人来说,在所有这些领域进行创业活动,而且又是在晚清的中国这样不顺利的境况之中,这些已经是不容否认的实际成就了。特别值得注意的是,他能一方面经营管理这些企业,一方面又要积极投入官场生涯。然而他所办的这些企业并不标志着中国经济的根本改革的开始。相反,它们的组成是同中国传统机构及其办事方法的妥协。它们的发展机会受制于外国的经济压力,官方的漠不关心甚至于贪婪掠夺、资金和人员的短缺,也受制于一种强调私人和家族关系超过合理的经济活动的价值标准。这些企业不可避免地依赖于其主人能为他们弄到手的专利垄断权。这些垄断权能够保证利润和外快,保护投资者的资本,但与扩大生产和长期发展却是不相容的。总之,盛宣怀所创办的近代企业,除开始时有所进展外,终于转变成为保护官僚资本的工具了。

All rights reserved@ENP-China